Friday 14 June 2013

Theory of money-Manish Padhi

                                    Theory of Money- Manish Padhi
A further step in the path of economic development to higher
levels of well-being can be regarded as having been taken when
the artisans themselves begin to procure the raw materials for their
products, even though they still produce these products for the
consumers only on order. This state of affairs can still, with few
exceptions, be observed in small towns, and to some extent even in
larger places in some trades. The artisan does not yet manufacture
products for later, and hence uncertain, sale. But he is already, to
the extent of his labor power, in a position to meet the needs of his
customers by making it unnecessary for them to expend efforts on
purchasing or producing raw materials in a frequently highly
uneconomic manner.
 But in scientific discourse a need was felt for a term designating
all economic goods held ready for sale without regard to their tangibility,
mobility, or character as products of labor, and without
regard to the persons offering them for sale. A large number of
economists, especially German economists, therefore defined commodities
as (economic) goods of any kind that are intended for sale.
The commodity concept in the popular sense is nevertheless of
importance not only because law-givers3 and a large number of
economists employ the term in the popular sense, but also because
some of those who are aware of the wider, scientific, sense of the
term sometimes employ this or that element of the narrower, popular,
meaning in their definitions.
Money is not the product of an agreement on the part of economizing
men nor the product of legislative acts. No one invented
it. As economizing individuals in social situations became
increasingly aware of their economic interest, they everywhere
attained the simple knowledge that surrendering less saleable
commodities for others of greater saleability brings them substantially
closer to the attainment of their specific economic
purposes. Thus, with the progressive development of social
economy, money came to exist in numerous centers of civilization
independently. But precisely because money is a natural
product of human economy, the specific forms in which it has appeared were everywhere and at all times the result of specific
and changing economic situations. Among the same people at different
times, and among different peoples at the same time, different
goods have attained the special position in trade described
above.
Money is not the product of an agreement on the part of economizing
men nor the product of legislative acts. No one invented
it. As economizing individuals in social situations became
increasingly aware of their economic interest, they everywhere
attained the simple knowledge that surrendering less saleable
commodities for others of greater saleability brings them substantially
closer to the attainment of their specific economic
purposes. Thus, with the progressive development of social
economy, money came to exist in numerous centers of civilization
independently
As the price of a commodity is the average cost of production, it includes the fact that a tiny proportion of commodities may be found, although finding goods is hardly typical of modern manufacturing processes.
Marginal utility as the source of value meant that the perceived need for an object was seen to be dictating the value, on an individual rather than a general level. The implication was that the individual mind is the source of economic value.
Although Menger accepted the marginal utility theory, he made deviations from the work of other neoclassical pioneers. Most importantly he fundamentally rejected the use of mathematical methods insisting that the function of economics was to investigate the essences rather than the specific quantities of economic phenomena.



No comments:

Post a Comment